Слайд 1Chapter Eighteen
Externalities, Open Access, and Public Goods
Слайд 2© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Externalities, Open Access, and
Public Goods
In this chapter, we examine six main topics
Externalities
The inefficiency of competition with externalities
Market structure and externalities
Allocating property rights to reduce externalities
Open-access common property
Public goods
Слайд 3© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Externalities
Externality
The direct effect of
the actions of a person or firm on another person’s well-being or a firm’s production capability rather than an indirect effect through changes in prices.
Слайд 4© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Externalities
Externalities may either help
or harm others.
An externality that harms someone is called a negative externality.
A positive externality benefits others.
Слайд 5© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
The inefficiency of competition
with externalities
Competitive firms and consumers do not have to pay for the harms of their negative externalities, so they create excessive amounts.
Because producers are not compensated for the benefits of a positive externality, too little of such externalities is produced.
Слайд 6© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
The inefficiency of competition
with externalities
Private cost
The cost of production only, not including externalities
Social cost
The private cost plus the cost of the harms from externalities
Слайд 7© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Supply-and-Demand Analysis
We use a
supply-and-demand diagram to illustrate that a competitive market produces excessive pollution because the firms’ private cost is less than their social cost.
Слайд 8© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.1 Welfare Effects
of Pollution in a Competitive Market
The competitive equilibrium, , is determined by the intersection of the demand curve and the competitive supply or private marginal cost curve, , which ignores the cost of pollution.
Слайд 9© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.1 Welfare Effects
of Pollution in a Competitive Market
The social optimum, , is at the intersection of the demand curve and the social marginal cost curve,
, where is the marginal cost of the pollution (gunk). Private producer surplus is based on curve, and social producer surplus is based on the curve.
Слайд 10© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.1 Welfare Effects
of Pollution in a Competitive Market
Demand
MC
p
MC
g
MC
g
MC
s
=
MC
p
+
MC
g
450
p
s
= 282
p
c
= 240
30
84
198
Q
c
=
105
Q
s
=
84
225
0
e
c
e
s
A
B
F
C
D
E
H
G
Q
, Tons of paper per day
MC
p
Слайд 11© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Supply-and-Demand Analysis
The figure illustrates
two main results with respect to negative externalities.
First, a competitive market produces excessive negative externalities.
Second, the optimal amount of pollution is greater than zero.
Слайд 12© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Reducing Externalities
Because competitive markets
produce too many negative externalities, government intervention may provide a social gain.
Слайд 13© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Table 18.1 Industrial CO2
Emissions, 2002
Слайд 14© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Reducing Externalities
If a government
has sufficient knowledge about pollution damage, the demand curve, costs, and the production technology, it can force a competitive market to produce the social optimum.
Слайд 15© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Reducing Externalities
A governmental limit
on the amount of air or water pollution that may be released is called an emission standard. A tax on air pollution is called an emissions fee, and a tax on discharges into the air or waterways is an effluent charge.
Слайд 16© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Reducing Externalities
Internalize the externality
To
bear the cost of the harm that one inflicts on others (or to capture the benefit that one provides to others)
Слайд 17© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.2 Taxes to
Control Pollution
Placing a tax on the firms equal to the harm the gunk, , causes them to internalize the externality, so their private marginal cost is the same as the social marginal cost, . As a result, the competitive after-tax equilibrium is the same as the social optimum, .
Слайд 18© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.2 Taxes to
Control Pollution
Alternatively, applying a specific tax of
per ton of paper, which is the marginal harm from the gunk at , also results in the social optimum.
Слайд 19© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.2 Taxes to
Control Pollution
Demand
MC
p
MC
g
MC
s
=
MC
p
+
t
(
Q
)
MC
p
+
τ
τ
=
84
450
p
s
= 282
MC
p
= 198
MC
g
= 84
Q
s
=
84
225
0
e
s
Q
, Tons of paper per day
Слайд 20© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Cost-Benefit Analysis
By using a
cost-benefit analysis, we obtain another interpretation of the pollution problem in terms of the marginal cost and benefit of the pollution itself.
Слайд 21© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Cost-Benefit Analysis
Welfare is maximized
by reducing output and pollution until the marginal benefit from less pollution equals the marginal cost of less output.
Слайд 22© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.3 Cost-Benefit Analysis
of Pollution
The benefit curve reflects the reduction in harm from pollution as the amount of gunk falls from the competitive level. The cost of reducing the amount of gunk is the fall in output, which reduces consumer surplus and private producer surplus. Welfare is maximized at 84 tons of paper and 84 units of gunk, the quantities at which the difference between the benefit and cost curves, the net benefit, is greatest.
Слайд 23© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.3 Cost-Benefit Analysis
of Pollution
The net benefit is maximized where the marginal benefit, , which is the slope of the benefit curve, equals the marginal cost, , the slope of the cost curve.
Слайд 24© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.3 Cost-Benefit Analysis
of Pollution
Cost: less paper
Benefit: less gunk
Maximum
net
benefit
84
63
105
0
84
105
G
, Units of gunk per day
Q
, Tons of paper per day
G
, Units of gunk per day
Q
, Tons of paper per day
(a) Cost and Benefit
(b) Marginal Cost and Marginal Benefit
4,000
2,000
105
84
0
MC
MB
Слайд 25© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Market Structure and Externalities
Two
of our main results concerning competitive markets and negative externalities—that too much pollution is produced and that a tax equal to the marginal social cost of the externality solves the problem—do not hold for other market structures.
Слайд 26© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Monopoly and Externalities
Although the
competitive market with an externality always produces more output than the social optimum, a monopoly may produce more than, the same as, or less than the social optimum.
Слайд 27© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Monopoly and Externalities
Which effect
dominates depends on the elasticity of demand for the output and on the extent of the marginal damage the pollution causes.
Слайд 28© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Monopoly Versus Competitive Welfare
with Externalities
In the absence of externalities, welfare is greater under competition than under an unregulated monopoly.
However, with an externality, welfare may be greater with monopoly than with competition.
Слайд 29© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.4 Monopoly, Competition,
and Social Optimum with Pollution
At the competitive equilibrium, , more is produced than at the social optimum, . As a result, the deadweight loss in the competitive market is . The monopoly equilibrium, , is determined by the intersection of the marginal revenue and the private marginal cost, , curves.
Слайд 30© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.4 Monopoly, Competition,
and Social Optimum with Pollution
The social welfare (based on the marginal social cost, , curve) under monopoly is . Here the deadweight loss of monopoly, , is less than the deadweight loss under competition, .
Слайд 31© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.4 Monopoly, Competition,
and Social Optimum with Pollution
Q
, Tons of paper per day
Demand
MR
MC
p
MC
g
MC
s
=
MC
p
+
MC
g
450
330
310
282
240
30
84
105
225
70
60
0
e
m
e
c
e
s
e
t
A
B
C
D
Слайд 32© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Taxing Externalities in Noncompetitive
Markets
Trying to solve a negative externality problem is more complex in a noncompetitive market than in a competitive market.
Слайд 33© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Taxing Externalities in Noncompetitive
Markets
To achieve a social optimum in a competitive market, the government only has to reduce the externality, possibly by decreasing output.
In a noncompetitive market, the government must eliminate problems arising from both externalities and the exercise of market power.
Слайд 34© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Allocating Property Rights to
Reduce Externalities
Instead of controlling externalities directly through emissions fees and emissions standards, the government may take an indirect approach by assigning a property right: an exclusive privilege to use an asset.
Слайд 35© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Allocating Property Rights to
Reduce Externalities
If no one holds a property right for a good or a bad, the good or bad is unlikely to have a price.
Слайд 36© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Allocating Property Rights to
Reduce Externalities
For many bads, such as pollution, and for some goods, property rights are not clearly defined. No one has exclusive property rights to the sir we breathe. Because of this lack of a price, a polluter’s private marginal cost of production is less than the full social marginal cost.
Слайд 37© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Coase Theorem
According to the
Coase Theorem (Coase, 1960), the optimal levels of pollution and output can result from bargaining between polluters and their victims if property rights are clearly defined.
Слайд 38© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Table 18.2 (a,b) Property
Rights and Bargaining
Слайд 39© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Table 18.2 (c) Property
Rights and Bargaining
Слайд 40© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Coase Theorem
If there are
no impediments to bargaining, assigning property rights results in the efficient outcome at which joint profits are maximized.
Efficiency is achieved regardless of who receives the property rights.
Слайд 41© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Coase Theorem
Who gets the
property rights affects the income distribution. The property rights are valuable. The party with the property rights may be compensated by the other party.
Слайд 42© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Problems with the Coase
Approach
First, if transaction costs are very high, it might not pay for the two sides to meet.
Second, if firms engage in strategic bargaining behavior, an agreement may not be reached.
Third, if either side lacks information about the costs or benefits or reducing pollution, a nonefficient outcome may occur.
Слайд 43© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Markets for Pollution
If high
transaction costs preclude bargaining, we may be able to overcome this problem by using a market, which facilitates exchanges between individuals.
Слайд 44© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Markets for Pollution
Under this
cap and trade system, the government gives firms permits, each of which confers the right to create a certain amount of pollution. Each firm may use its permits or sell them to other firms.
Слайд 45© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Markets for Pollution
Bu using
a market, the government does not have to collect this type of detailed information to achieve efficiency. Its only decision concerns what total amount of pollution to allow.
Слайд 46© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Open-Access Common Property
Open-Access Common
Property
Resources to which everyone has free access
Слайд 47© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Overuse of Open-Access Common
Property
Because people do not have to pay to use open-access common property resources, they are overused.
e.g.
Common Pools.
The Internet.
Roads
Fisheries.
Слайд 48© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Solving the Commons Problem
Government
Regulation of Commons
Overuse of a common resource occurs because individuals do not bear the full social cost. However, by applying a tax or fee equal to the externality harm that each individual imposes on others, a government forces each person to internalize the externality.
Слайд 49© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Solving the Commons Problem
Government
Regulation of Commons
Alternatively, the government can restrict access to the commons. One typical approach is to grant access on a first-come, first-served basis.
Слайд 50© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Solving the Commons Problem
Assigning
Property Rights
An alternative approach to resolving the commons problem is to assign private property rights.
Слайд 51© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Public Goods
Public Good
A commodity
or service whose consumption by one person does not preclude others from also consuming it
Слайд 52© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Table 18.3 Rivalry and
Слайд 53© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Markets for public goods
exist only if nonpurchasers can be excluded from consuming them.
Markets do not exist for nonexclusive public goods.
If the government does not provide a nonexclusive public good, no one provides it.
Markets for Public Goods
Слайд 54© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Demand for Public Goods
Because
a public good lacks rivalry, many people can get pleasure from the same unit of output. As a consequence, the social demand curve or willingness-to-pay curve for a public good is the vertical sum of the demand curves of each individual.
Слайд 55© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.5 Inadequate Provision
of a Public Good
Security guards protect both tenants of the mall. If each guard costs $10 per hour, the television store, with demand , is willing to hire four guards per hour. The ice-cream parlor, with demand , is not willing to hire any guards.
Слайд 56© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.5 Inadequate Provision
of a Public Good
Thus if everyone acts independently, the equilibrium is . The social demand for this public good is the vertical sum of the individual demand curves, . Thus the social optimum is , at which five guards are hired.
Слайд 57© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Figure 18.5 Inadequate Provision
of a Public Good
Guards per hour
Supply,
MC
25
18
13
10
8
7
3
2
5
7
9
4
0
e
p
e
s
D
1
D
D
2
Слайд 58© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Free Riding
Many people are
unwilling to pay for their share of a public good. They try to get others to pay for it, so they can free ride: benefit from the actions of others without paying.
Слайд 59© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Table 18.4 Private Payments
for a Public Good
Слайд 60© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Free Riding
In each of
these games, the Nash equilibrium is for neither store to hire a guard because of free riding. The nonoptimal outcome occurs for the same reason as in other prisoners’ dilemma games: The stores don’t do what is best for them collectively when they act independently.
Слайд 61© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Reducing Free Riding
Governmental or
other collective actions can reduce free riding.
Methods that may be used include social pressure, merges, compulsion, and privatization.
Слайд 62© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Valuing Public Goods
To ensure
that a nonexclusive public good is provided, a government usually produces it or compels others to do so. Issues that a government faces in providing such a public good include whether to provide it at all and, if so, how much to provide.
Слайд 63© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Table 18.5 Voting on
$300 Traffic Signals
Слайд 64© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
Valuing Public Goods
The problem
with yes-no votes is that they ignore the intensity of preferences.
Thus such majority voting fails to value the public good fully and hence does not guarantee that it is efficiently provided.